Nudge theory: what 15 years of research tells us about its promises and politics

Categories
Applied Institute for Research in Economics

Dr Stuart Mills is a Lecturer in Economics at Leeds University Business School. His research interests include behavioural economics, nudge theory, Artificial Intelligence, behavioural public policymaking, digital economy, and economic philosophy.

Abstract image of shoppers

This article originally appeared on The Conversation on 6 September 2023.

<p>It’s been 15 years since a particular concept of behavioural science went mainstream. “<a href="https://www.imperial.ac.uk/nudgeomics/about/what-is-nudge-theory/">Nudge theory</a>”, the notion that our behaviour can be successfully influenced through “soft” interventions, has subsequently appealed to plenty of people seeking to change the way we live. </p>

<p>The 2008 book which set out the idea – <a href="https://www.penguin.co.uk/books/56784/nudge-by-richard-h-thaler-cass-r-sunstein/9780141999937">Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth and Happiness</a> – sold more than 2 million copies. But its influence went way beyond sales figures. </p>

<p>The authors – behavioural economist Richard Thaler and law professor Cass Sunstein – inspired powerful politicians, including former US president <a href="https://behavioralscientist.org/executive-order-formally-establishes-us-nudge-unit/">Barack Obama</a> and former UK prime minister <a href="https://www.theguardian.com/politics/2010/nov/12/david-cameron-nudge-unit">David Cameron</a> to set up government teams with the specific remit of incorporating nudge theory into public policy. </p>

<p>These “nudge units” became widespread, with recent research suggesting there are now over <a href="https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.3982/ECTA18709">200 of them</a> around the world. But while teams of policymakers appear happy to have been taking their “<a href="https://podcasts.apple.com/us/podcast/nudge-part-1-a-simple-solution-for-littering-organ/id1651876897?i=1000611711937">nudge-pills</a>”, making small changes to our decision-making processes, the success of those carefully designed nudges is by no means universally agreed. </p>

<p>Back in 2008 though, whether or not nudges actually worked was rarely discussed. The book was packed with peer-reviewed studies, and set out an idea that was broad enough for many readers to relate to. It felt intuitive. </p>

<p>Instead, criticism of nudging at the time typically focused on concerns that government nudges <a href="https://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s10603-014-9265-1">undermined individual freedom</a>. The worry was that if nudges could lead to major changes in personal decision-making and be used to influence citizen behaviour, then this created the risk of <a href="https://doi.org/10.1080/13571510903227064">illegitimate state overreach</a> – maybe even <a href="https://iea.org.uk/blog/a-nudge-towards-totalitarianism-0">totalitarianism</a>.</p>

<p>These days, while some questions remain about individual freedom, they are not as prominent. One reason appears to be a general acceptance that some government influence on citizens and the decisions they make <a href="https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4357437">is surely inevitable</a>. But there is also the fact that <a href="https://www.ft.com/content/a23e808b-e293-4cc0-b077-9168cff135e4">a large amount of evidence</a> questions whether nudges actually work at all. </p>

<p>After 15 years, plenty of nudge studies can now be assessed to get a better sense of whether this seemingly revolutionary idea really delivers. 
Behavioural economists undertake this assessment using an approach called “meta-analysis”, which combines multiple studies to get the most reliable data. Last year, <a href="https://www.pnas.org/doi/10.1073/pnas.2200300119">one major meta-analysis</a> reported finding no evidence of nudges working. </p>

<p><a href="https://theconversation.com/nudge-theory-doesnt-work-after-all-says-new-evidence-review-but-it-could-still-have-a-future-187635">This was a big deal</a>. And although the study had its own critics, who say it does not properly <a href="https://behavioralscientist.org/making-sense-of-the-do-nudges-work-debate/">account for context</a>, the analysis also supported <a href="https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/abs/10.3982/ECTA18709">previous evidence</a> of publication bias, suggesting researchers have been cherry picking the “good” nudge studies to publish for years. </p>

<p>Nudge theory has also been undermined elsewhere by doubts raised around the <a href="https://doi.org/10.1038/s41562-016-0021">usefulness of findings</a> in behavioural science and psychology, as well as high-profile scandals involving <a href="https://www.ft.com/content/846cc7a5-12ee-4a44-830e-11ad00f224f9">allegations of data fabrication</a>. </p>

<h2>Pushing back against nudging</h2>

<p>Critics of nudge theory have two key arguments. One is the notion that nudges have small (if any) effects on our behaviour, and are therefore <a href="https://doi.org/10.1111/padm.12941">ineffective policy tools</a>.  </p>

<p>Their second point is that nudge-based acts are open to being used by vested interests to <a href="https://doi.org/10.1017/S0140525X22002023">distract policymakers</a> and the public from actually effective solutions – that they put the emphasis on slight changes from individuals instead of more meaningful and effective systemic change.</p>

<p>For instance, nudges that encourage households to <a href="https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/abs/10.1111/j.1467-9280.2007.01917.x">reduce their energy consumption</a> may be considered a good idea. But what if this nudge also <a href="https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4426034">reduces the political will</a> to pursue more effective (and expensive) policies, such as retrofitting homes or dramatically investing in sources of sustainable energy?</p>

<p>Even supporters of nudge theory have conceded that <a href="https://www.ft.com/content/91f2a55b-66b2-4573-af5a-afa0deb16f5f">nudges may have overpromised</a> in the past. A recent <a href="https://doi.org/10.1038/s41562-023-01555-3">behavioural science “manifesto”</a> argues that behavioural economists should “be humble” about limits of nudge theory. And in a 2021 updated edition of their <a href="https://www.penguinbookshop.com/book/9780143137009">famous book</a>, Thaler and Sunstein – who never anticipated the <a href="https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=FEkfqQAp6wk">phenomenal reach they achieved</a> – argue that nudges are always part of the solution, but <a href="https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=FEkfqQAp6wk">rarely the solution itself</a>. </p>

<figure class="align-center ">
            <img alt="Barack Obama" src="https://images.theconversation.com/files/544835/original/file-20230825-21-cvkuma.jpg?ixlib=rb-1.1.0&q=45&auto=format&w=754&fit=clip" srcset="https://images.theconversation.com/files/544835/original/file-20230825-21-cvkuma.jpg?ixlib=rb-1.1.0&q=45&auto=format&w=600&h=400&fit=crop&dpr=1 600w, https://images.theconversation.com/files/544835/original/file-20230825-21-cvkuma.jpg?ixlib=rb-1.1.0&q=30&auto=format&w=600&h=400&fit=crop&dpr=2 1200w, https://images.theconversation.com/files/544835/original/file-20230825-21-cvkuma.jpg?ixlib=rb-1.1.0&q=15&auto=format&w=600&h=400&fit=crop&dpr=3 1800w, https://images.theconversation.com/files/544835/original/file-20230825-21-cvkuma.jpg?ixlib=rb-1.1.0&q=45&auto=format&w=754&h=503&fit=crop&dpr=1 754w, https://images.theconversation.com/files/544835/original/file-20230825-21-cvkuma.jpg?ixlib=rb-1.1.0&q=30&auto=format&w=754&h=503&fit=crop&dpr=2 1508w, https://images.theconversation.com/files/544835/original/file-20230825-21-cvkuma.jpg?ixlib=rb-1.1.0&q=15&auto=format&w=754&h=503&fit=crop&dpr=3 2262w" sizes="(min-width: 1466px) 754px, (max-width: 599px) 100vw, (min-width: 600px) 600px, 237px">
            <figcaption>
              <span class="caption">Nudge, nudge.</span>
              <span class="attribution"><a class="source" href="https://www.shutterstock.com/image-photo/charlotte-nc-usa-july-5-2016-462060448">Evan El-Amin/Shutterstock</a></span>
            </figcaption>
          </figure>

<p>In the political sphere though, nudge theory will probably continue to prosper, as a way of gaining political capital from cheap solutions to <a href="https://www.ft.com/content/91f2a55b-66b2-4573-af5a-afa0deb16f5f">difficult problems</a>. For instance, the nudge of automatically enrolling UK workers into pension schemes (they have the right to opt out) has <a href="https://ifs.org.uk/articles/automatic-enrolment-too-successful-nudge-boost-pension-saving">substantially increased</a> the number of people saving for retirement, an ambition of both Labour and Conservative governments. </p>

<p>This policy uses a common type of nudge known as a “<a href="https://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s10551-020-04731-x">default option</a>”, which relies on people’s tendency to <a href="https://doi.org/10.1016%2Fj.jenvp.2007.09.004">accept the status quo</a>. Before automatic enrolment, employers were still obliged to provide a pension scheme, but employees had to request access to it. </p>

<p>But even when nudged in this soft, almost passive way, people probably <a href="https://doi.org/10.1111/padm.12941">aren’t saving enough</a> – mainly because they can’t afford to. Fundamental pension reform or a radical change to wealth distribution is politically challenging and expensive, whereas nudging workers into passive enrolment is not.</p>

<p>Nudges are also less controversial to the electorate than a new ban or mandate. A gentle push towards <a href="https://doi.org/10.1038/s41467-019-12457-2">more environmentally friendly behaviour</a> is likely to provoke less backlash among voters than a government ordering people to change the way they do things.</p>

<p>In this sense then, nudges remain useful political tools. They are cheap, and they neither ban nor mandate. And if they don’t work, it takes a while for voters to notice. </p>

<p>So perhaps nudges do not even need to work to continue to have a role in modern society, because politicians will always demand a tool like them for <a href="https://www.ft.com/content/0e6f1088-6280-11dd-9a1e-000077b07658">their political ends</a>. It is an argument that could nudge nudging along for at least another 15 years.<!-- Below is The Conversation's page counter tag. Please DO NOT REMOVE. --><img src="https://counter.theconversation.com/content/210534/count.gif?distributor=republish-lightbox-basic" alt="The Conversation" width="1" height="1" style="border: none !important; box-shadow: none !important; margin: 0 !important; max-height: 1px !important; max-width: 1px !important; min-height: 1px !important; min-width: 1px !important; opacity: 0 !important; outline: none !important; padding: 0 !important" referrerpolicy="no-referrer-when-downgrade" /><!-- End of code. If you don't see any code above, please get new code from the Advanced tab after you click the republish button. The page counter does not collect any personal data. More info: https://theconversation.com/republishing-guidelines --></p>

<p><span><a href="https://theconversation.com/profiles/stuart-mills-884987">Stuart Mills</a>, Assistant Professor of Economics, <em><a href="https://theconversation.com/institutions/university-of-leeds-1122">University of Leeds</a></em></span></p>

<p>This article is republished from <a href="https://theconversation.com">The Conversation</a> under a Creative Commons license. Read the <a href="https://theconversation.com/nudge-theory-what-15-years-of-research-tells-us-about-its-promises-and-politics-210534">original article</a>.</p>
 

Contact us

If you would like to get in touch regarding any of these blog entries, or are interested in contributing to the blog, please contact:

Email: research.lubs@leeds.ac.uk
Phone: +44 (0)113 343 8754

Click here to view our privacy statement

The views expressed in this article are those of the author and may not reflect the views of Leeds University Business School or the University of Leeds.